Thursday, August 8, 2013
Dividends Versus Capital Gains : What Do Investors Prefer?
When deciding how much cash to
distribute to stockholders, financial managers must keep in mind that the
firm’s objective is to maximize shareholder value. Consequently, the target
payout ratio-defined as the percentage of net income to be paid out as cash
dividends –should be based in large part on investors, preferences for
dividends versus capital gains: do investors prefer (1) to have the firm
distribute income as cash dividends or (2) to have it either repurchase stock
or else plow the earnings back into the business, both of which should result
in capital gains? This preference can be considered in terms of the constant
growth stock valuation model:
D1
P0 = -------------
Ks - g
If the company increases the
payout ratio, it raises D1. This increase in the numerator, taken
alone, would cause the stock price to rise. However, if D1 is
raised, then less money will be available for reinvestment, that will cause the
expected growth rate to decline, and that would tend to lower the stock’s
price. Thus any change in payout policy will have two opposing effects.
Therefore, the firm’s optimal dividend policy must strike a balance between
current dividends and future growth so as to maximize the stock price.
In this section we examine three
theories of investor preference: (1) the dividend irrelevance theory, (2) the “bird-in-the-hand”
theory and (3) the tax preference theory.
Dividend Irrelevance Theory
It has been argued that dividend
policy has no effect on either the price of a firm’s stock or its cost of
capital. If dividend policy has no significant effects, then it would be
irrelevant. The principal proponents of the dividend irrelevance theory are Merton
Miller and Franco Modigliani (MM)1. They argued that the firm’s
value is determined only by its basic earning power and its business risk. In
other words, MM argued that the value of the firm depends only on the income
produced by its assets not on how this income is split between dividends and retained
earnings.
To understand MM’s argument that
dividend policy is irrelevant, recognize that any shareholder can construct his
or her own dividend policy. For example, if a firm does not pay dividends, a
shareholder who wants a 5 percent dividend can “create” it by selling 5 percent
of his or her stock. Conversely, if a company pays a higher dividend than an
investor desires, the investor can use the unwanted dividends to buy additional
shares of the company’s stock. If investors could buy and sell shares and thus
create their own dividend policy without incurring costs, then the firm’s
dividend policy would truly be irrelevant. Note, though that investors who want
additional dividends must incur brokerage costs to sell shares, and investors
who do not want dividends must first pay taxes on the unwanted dividends and
then incur brokerage costs to purchase shares with the after-tax dividends.
Since taxes and brokerage costs certainly exist, dividend policy may well be
relevant.
In developing their dividend
theory. MM made a number of assumptions, especially the absence of taxes and
brokerage costs. Obviously, taxes and brokerage costs do exist, so the MM
irrelevance theory may not be true. However, MM argued (correctly) that all
economic theories are based on simplifying assumptions, and that the validity
of a theory must be judged by empirical tests, not by the realism of its
assumptions. We will discuss empirical tests of MM’s dividend irrelevance
theory shortly.
Bird-in-the-Hand Theory
The principal conclusion of MM’s
dividend irrelevance theory is that dividend policy does not affect the
required rate of return on equity Ks. This conclusion has been hotly
debated in academic circles. In particular, Myron Gordon and John Lintner
argued that Ks decreases as the dividend payout is increased because
investors are less certain of receiving the capital gains which are supposed to
result from retaining earnings than they are of receiving dividend payments.2
Gordon and Lintner said, in effect that investors value a dollar of expected
dividends more highly than a dollar of expected capital gains because the
dividend yield component, D1/P0, is less risky than the g
component in the total expected return equation, Ks=D1/P0
+ g.
MM disagreed. They argued that Ks
is independent of dividend policy, which implies that investors are indifferent
between D1/P0 and g and, hence, between dividends and
capital gains. MM called the Gordon-Lintner argument the bird-in-the-hand
fallacy because, in MM’s view, most investors plan to reinvest their dividends
in the stock of the same or similar firms, and in any event the riskiness of
the firm’s cash flows to investors in the long run is determined by the
riskiness of operating cash flows not by dividend payout policy.
Tax Preference Theory
There are three tax-related
reasons for thinking that investors might prefer a low dividend payout to a
high payout: (1) Long-term capital gains are taxed at a maximum rate of 28
percent, whereas dividend income is taxed at effective rates which go up to
39.6 percent. Therefore, wealthy investors (who own most of the stock and
receive most of the dividends) might prefer to have companies retain and plow
earnings back into the business. Earnings growth would presumably lead to stock
price increases, and lower-taxed capital gains would be substituted fro
higher-taxed dividends. (2) Taxes are not paid on the gain until a stock is
sold. Due to time value effects, a dollar of taxes paid in the future has a
lower effective cost than a dollar paid today. (3) If a stock is held by
someone until he or she dies, no capital gains tax is due at all-the
beneficiaries who receive the stock can use the stocks’ value on the death day
as their cost basis and thus completely escape the capital gains tax.
Because of these tax advantages,
investors may prefer to have companies retain most of their earnings. If so
investors would be willing to pay more for low-payout companies than for
otherwise similar high-payout companies.
Subscribe to:
Post Comments (Atom)
0 comments:
Post a Comment