Saturday, August 31, 2013
Credit Policy
The success or failure of a
business depends primarily on the demand for its products as a rule, the higher
its sales, the larger its profits and the higher its stock price. Sales, in
turn, depend on a number of factors, some exogenous but others under the firm’s
control. The major controllable determinants of demand are sales prices,
product quality, advertising and the firm’s credit policy. Credit policy in
turn, consists of these four variables.
1. Credit period, which is the length of time buyers are given
to pay for their purchases.
2. Credit standards, which refer to the
required financial strength of acceptable credit customers.
3. Collection policy, which is measured by its
toughness or laxity in attempting to collect on slow-paying accounts.
4. Discounts given for early payment, including
the discount percentage and how rapidly payment must be made to qualify for the
discount.
The credit manager is responsible
for administering the firm’s credit policy. However, because of the pervasive
importance of credit, the credit policy itself is normally established by the
executive committee, which usually consists of the president plus the
vice-presidents of finance, marketing and production.
Saturday, August 24, 2013
Marketable Securities
Realistically the management of
cash and marketable securities cannot be separated-management of one implies
management of the other. We focused on cash management. Now we turn to
marketable securities.
Marketable securities typically
provide much lower yields than operating assets. For example, recently Chrysler
held a $8.7 billion portfolio of short-term marketable securities that yielded
about 6 percent but its operating assets provided a return of about 14 percent.
Why would a company such as Chrysler have such large holdings of low-yielding
assets?
In many cases, companies hold
marketable securities for the same reasons they hold cash. Although these
securities are not the same as cash, in most cases they can be converted to cash
on very short notice (often just a few minutes) with a single telephone call.
Moreover, while cash an most commercial checking accounts yield northing,
marketable securities provide at least a modest return. For this reason, many
firms hold at least some marketable securities in lieu of larger cash balances,
liquidating part of the portfolio to increase the cash account when cash
outflows exceed inflows. In such situations the marketable securities could be
used as a substitute for transactions balances, for precautionary balances for
speculative balances or for all three. In most cases the securities are held
primarily for precautionary purposes most firms prefer to rely on bank credit
to make temporary transactions or to meet speculative needs, but they may still
hold some liquid assets to guard against a possible shortage of bank credit.
A few years ago Chrysler had
essentially no cash it was incurring huge losses and those losses had drained
its cash account. Then a new management team took over improved operations and
began generating positive cash flows, Chryslers cash (and marketable
securities) was up to $8.7 billion, and analysts were forecasting a further
buildup over the next year or so to more than $10 billion. Management
indicated, in various statements, that the cash hoard was necessary to enable
the company to weather the next downturn in auto sales.
Although setting the target cash
balance is to a large extent judgmental analytical rules can be applied to help
formulate better judgments. For example, years ago William Baumol recognized
that the trade-off between cash and marketable securities is similar to the one
firms face when setting the optimal level of inventory. Baumol applied the EOQ
inventory model to determine the optimal level of cash balances, he suggested
that cash holdings should be higher if costs are high and the time to liquidate
marketable securities is long, but that those holdings should be lower if
interest rates are low. His logic was that if it is expensive and time consuming
to convert securities to cash and if securities do not earn much because interest
rates are low, then it does not pay to hold securities as opposed to cash. It
does pay to hold securities if interest rates are high and the securities can
be converted to cash quickly and cheaply.
Saturday, August 17, 2013
Cash Management Techniques
Cash management has changed significantly
over the last 20 years for two reasons. First, from the early 1970s to the
mid-1980s, there was an upward tread in interest rates which increased the
opportunity cost of holding cash. This encouraged financial managers to search
for more efficient ways of managing cash. Second, technological developments,
particularly computerized electronic funds transfer mechanisms, changed the way
cash is managed.
Most cash management activities
are performed jointly by the firm and its banks. Effective cash management
encompasses proper management of cash inflows and outflows, which entails (1)
synchronizing cash flows, (2) using float, (3) accelerating collections, (4)
getting available funds to where they are needed, and (5) controlling
disbursements. Most business is conducted by large firms, many of which operate
regionally, nationally, or even globally. They collect cash from many sources
and make payments from a number of different cities or even countries. For
example, companies such as IBM, General Motors, and Hewlett Packard have
manufacturing plants all around the world, even more sales officers, and bank
accounts in virtually every city where they do business. Their collection
points follow sales patterns. Some disbursements are made from local offices,
but most are made in the cities where manufacturing occurs, or else from the
home office. Thus, a major corporation might have hundreds or ever thousands of
bank accounts and since there is no reason to thinks that inflows and outflows
will balance in each account, a system must be in place to transfer funds from
where they come in to where they are needed, to arrange loans to cover net
corporate shortfalls, and to invest net corporate surpluses without delay. We discuss
the most commonly used techniques for accomplishing these tasks in the
following sections.
Cash Flow Synchronization
If you as an individual were to
receive income once a year, you would probably put it in the bank, draw down
your account periodically, and have an average balance during the year equal to
about half your annual income. If you received income monthly instead of once a
year, you would operate similarly, but now your average balance would be much
smaller. If you could arrange to receive income daily and to pay rent, tuition,
and other charges on a daily basis, and if you were confident of your
forecasted inflows and outflows, then you could hold a very small average cash
balance.
Exactly the same situation holds
for businesses – by improving their forecasts and by arranging things so that
cash receipts coincide with cash requirements, firms can reduce their
transactions balances to a minimum. Recognizing all this, utility companies,
oil companies, credit card companies and so on, arrange to bill customers and
to pay their own bills, on regular “billing cycles” throughout the month. This
synchronization of cash flows provides cash when it is needed and thus enables
firms to reduce cash balances, decrease bank loans, lower interest expenses,
and boost profits.
Speed up the Check-Clearing
Process
When a customer writes and mails
a check, this does not mean that the funds are immediately available to the
receiving firm. Most to us have been told by someone that “the check is in the
mail”, and we have also deposited a check in our account and then been told
that we cannot write our own checks against this deposit until the check-clearing
process has been completed. Our bank must first make sure that the check we
deposited is good and the funds are available before it will give us cash.
In practice, it may take a long
time for a firm to process incoming checks and obtain the use of the money. A
check must first be delivered through the mail and then be cleared through the
banking system before the money can be put to use. Checks received from customers
in distant cities are especially subject to delays because of mail time and
also because more parties are involved. For example, assume that we receive a
check and deposit it in our bank. Our bank must send the check to the bank on
which it was drawn. Only when this latter bank transfers funds to our bank are
the funds available for us to use. Checks are generally cleared through the
Federal Reserve System or through a clearinghouse set up by the banks in a
particular city. Of course, if the check is deposited in the same bank on which
it was drawn, that bank merely transfers funds by bookkeeping entries from one
depositor to another. The length of time required for checks to clear is thus a
function of the distance between the payer’s and the payee’s banks. In the case
of private clearinghouses, it can range from one to three days. Checks are
generally cleared through the Federal Reserve System in about two days, but
mail delays can slow down things on each end of the Fed’s involvement in the
process.
Wednesday, August 14, 2013
The Cash Budget
The firm estimates its needs for
cash as a part of its general budgeting, or forecasting, process. First, it
forecasts sales, its fixed asset and inventory requirements, and the times when
payments must be made. This information is combined with projections about when
accounts receivable will be collected, tax payment dates, dividend and interest
payment dates, and so on. All of this information is summarized in the cash
budget, which shows the firm’s projected cash inflows and outflows over
some specified period. Generally, firms use a monthly cash budget forecasted
over the next year, plus a more detailed daily or weekly cash budget for the
coming month. The monthly cash budgets are used for planning purposes, and the
daily or weekly budgets for actual cash control.
The cash budget provides more
detailed information concerning a firm’s future cash flows than do the
forecasted financial statements. We developed Allied Food Products 2012
forecasted financial statements. Allied projected 2012 sales were $3,300
million, resulting in a net cash flow from operations of $162 million. When all
expenditures and financing flows are considered, Allied cash account is
projected to increase by $1 million in 2012. Does this mean that Allied will
not have to worry about cash shortages during 2012? To answer this question, we
must construct Allied cash budget for 2012.
To simplify the example, we will
only consider Allied cash budget for the last half of 2012. Further, we will
not list every cash flow but rather focus on the operating cash flows. Allied
sales peak is in September, shortly after the majority of its raw food inputs
have been harvested. All sales are made on terms of 2/10, net 40, meaning that
a 2 percent discount is allowed if payment is made within 10 days, and if the
discount is not taken, the full amount is due in 40 days. However, like most
companies, Allied finds that some of its customers delay payment up to 90 days.
Experience has shown that payment on 20 percent of Allied dollar sales is made
during the month in which the sale is made – these are the discount sales. On
70 percent of sales, payment is made during the month immediately following the
month of sale, and on 10 percent of sales payment is made in the second month
following the month of sale.
The costs to Allied of
foodstuffs, spices, preservatives, and packaging materials average 70 percent
of the sales prices of the finished products. These purchases are generally
made one month before the firm expects to sell the finished products, but
Allied purchase terms with its suppliers allow it to delay payments for 30
days. Accordingly, if July sales are forecasted at $300 million, then purchases
during June will amount to $210 million, and this amount will actually be paid
in July.
Such other cash expenditures as wages
and rent are also built into the cash budget, and Allied must make estimated
tax payments of $30 million on September 15 and $20 million on December 15.
Also, a $100 million payment for a new plant must be made in October. Assuming
that Allied target cash balance is $10 million, and that it projects $15
million to be on hand on July 1, 2012, what will its monthly cash surpluses or
short fails be for the period from July to December?
Tuesday, August 13, 2013
Stock Dividends and Stock Splits
Stock dividends and stock splits
are related to the firm’s cash dividend policy. The rationale for stock
dividends and splits can best be explained through an example. We will use Porter
Electronic Controls Inc, a $700 million electronic components manufacturer, for
this purpose. Since its inception, Porter’s markets have been expanding and the
company has enjoyed growth in sales and earnings. Some of its earnings have
been paid out in dividends, but some are also retained each year, causing its
earnings per share and stock price to grow. The company began its life with
only a few thousand shares outstanding, and after some years of growth, each of
Porter’s shares had a very high EPS and DPS. When a ‘normal’ P/E ratio was
applied, the derived market price was so high that few people could afford to
buy a “round lot” of 100 shares. This limited the demand for the stock and thus
kept the total market value of the firm below what it would have been if more
shares, at a lower price had been outstanding. To correct this situation,
Porter “split its stock” as described in the next section.
Stock Splits
Although there is little
empirical evidence to support the contention, there is nevertheless a
widespread belief in financial circles that an optimal price range exists for
stocks. “Optimal” means that if the price is within this range, the
price/earnings ratio, hence the firm’s value will be maximized. Many observers,
including Porter’s management, believe that the best range for most stocks is
from $20 to $80 per share. Accordingly if the price of Porter’s stock rose to
$80, management would probably declare a two-for-one stock split, thus doubling
the number of shares outstanding halving the earnings and dividends per share,
and thereby lowering the stock price. Each stockholder would have more shares,
but each share would be worth less. If the post-split price were $40, Porter’s
stockholders would be exactly as well off as they were before the split,
However, if the stock price were to stabilize above $40, stockholders would be
better off. Stock splits can be of any size-for example, the stock could be
split two-for-one, three-for-one, one-and-a half-for-one, or in any other way.
Stock Dividends
Stock dividends are similar to
stock splits in that they “divide the pie into smaller slices” without
affecting the fundamental position of the current stockholders. On a 5 percent
stock dividend, the holder of 100 shares would receive an additional 5 shares (without
cost); on a 20 percent stock dividend the same holder would receive 20 new
shares; and so on. Again, the total number of shares is increased so earnings
dividends and price per share all decline.
If a firm wants to reduce the
price of its stock, should it use a stock split or a stock dividend? Stock
splits are generally used after a sharp price run-up to produce a large price
reduction. Stock dividends used on a regular annual basis will keep the stock
price more or less constrained. For example, if a firm’s earnings and dividends
were growing at about 10 percent per year, its stock price would tend to go up
at about that same rate, and it would soon be outside the desired trading
range. A 10 percent annual stock dividend would maintain the stock price within
the optimal trading range. Note, though that small stock dividends create
bookkeeping problems and unnecessary expenses so firms today use stock splits
far more often than stock dividends.
Monday, August 12, 2013
Dividend Stability
The stability of dividends is
also important. Profits and cash flows vary over time, as do investment
opportunities. Taken alone, this suggests that corporations should vary their
dividends over time, increasing them when cash flows are large and the need for
funds is low and lowering them when cash is in short supply relative to
investment opportunities. However, many stockholders rely on dividends to meet
expenses and they would be seriously inconvenienced if the dividend stream were
unstable. Further reducing dividends to make funds available for capital
investment could send incorrect signals and that could drive down stock prices.
Thus, maximizing its stock price requires a firm to balance its internal needs
for funds against the needs and desires of its stockholders.
How should this balance be
struck: that is, how stable and dependable should a firm attempt to make its
dividends? It is impossible to give a definitive answer to this question, but
the following points are relevant:
1. Virtually every publicly owned company makes
a five to ten year financial forecast of earnings and dividends. Such forecasts
are never made public they are used for internal planning purposes only.
However, security analysts construct similar forecasts and do make them available
to investors; see value line for an example. Further, virtually every internal
five to ten year corporate forecast we have seen for a normal company projects
a trend of higher earnings and dividends. Both managers and investors know that
economic conditions may cause actual results to differ from forecasted results,
but “normal” companies expect to grow.
2.
Years ago, when inflation was not
persistent, the term “stable dividend policy” meant a policy of paying the same
dollar dividend year after year. AT&T was a prime example of a company with
a stable dividend policy - it paid $9 per year ($2.25 per quarter) for 25
straight years. Today, though most companies and stockholders expect earnings
to grow over time as a result of retained earnings and inflation. Further,
dividends are normally expected to grow more or less in line with earnings.
Thus today a “stable dividend policy” generally means increasing the dividend
at a reasonably steady rate. For example, Rubbermaid made this statement in a
recent annual report:
Dividends per share were
increased for the 34th consecutive year out goal is to increase
sales, earnings and per share by 15% per year, while achieving a 21% return on
beginning shareholders equity. It is also the Company’s objective to pay
approximately 30% of current year’s earnings as dividends, which will permit us
to retain sufficient capital to provide for future growth.
Rubbermaid used the word “approximately”
in discussing its payout ratio because ever if earnings vary a bit from the
target level the company still planned to increase the dividend by the target
growth rate. Even though Rubbermaid did not mention the dividend growth rate in
the statement, analysts can calculate the growth rate and see that it is the
same 15 percent as indicated for sales and earnings:
g=b(ROE)
=(1-Payout) (ROE)
=0.7(21%)=15%
Here b is the fraction of
earnings that are retained, or 1.0 minus the payout ratio.
Companies with volatile earnings
and cash flows would be reluctant to make a commitment to increase the dividend
each year so they would not make such a detailed statement even so most
companies would like to be able to exhibit the kind of stability Rubbermaid has
shown, and they try to come as close to it as they can.
Dividend stability has two
components: (1) How dependable is the growth rate, and (2) can we count on at
least receiving the current dividend in the future? The most stable policy,
from an investor’s standpoint, is that of a firm whose dividend growth rate is
predictable such a company’s total return (dividend yield plus capital gains
yield) would be relatively stable over the long run, and its stock would be a
good hedge against inflation. The second most stable policy is where
stockholders can be reasonably sure that the current dividend will not be
reduced it may not grow at a steady rate, but management will probably be able
to avoid cutting the dividend. The least stable situation is where earnings and
cash flows are so volatile that investors cannot count on the company to
maintain the current dividend over a typical business cycle.
3.
Most observers believe that dividend
stability is desirable. Assuming this position is correct; investors prefer
stocks that pay more predictable dividends to stocks which pay the same average
amount of dividends but in a more erratic manner. This means that the cost of
equity will be minimized and the stock price maximized, if a firm stabilizes
its dividends as much as possible.
Sunday, August 11, 2013
Other Dividend Policy Issues
Before we discuss how dividend
policy is set in practice, we must examine two other theoretical issues that could
affect our views toward dividend policy: (1) the information content or
signaling hypothesis and (2) the clientele effect.
Information Content, or
Signaling, Hypothesis
When MM set forth their dividend
irrelevance theory, they assumed that every-one investors and managers alike
has identical information regarding the firm’s future earnings and dividend. In
reality, however, different investors have different views on both the level of
future dividend payments and the uncertainty inherent in those payments and
managers have better information about future prospects than public
stockholders.
It has been observed that an increase
in the dividend is often accompanied by an increase in the price of a stock
while a dividend cut generally leads to a stock price decline. This could
indicate that investors, in the aggregate, prefer dividends to capital gains.
However, MM argued differently. They noted the well-established fact that
corporations are reluctant to cut dividends, hence do not raise dividends
unless they anticipate higher earnings in the future. Thus, MM argued that a
higher-than-expected dividend increase is a “signal” to investors that the firm’s
management forecasts good future earnings.4 Conversely a dividend
reduction or a smaller-than-expected increase, is a signal that management is
forecasting poor earnings in the future. Thus MM argued that investor’s
reactions to changes in dividend policy do not necessarily show that investors
prefer dividends to retained earnings. Rather, they argue that price changes
following dividend actions simply indicate that there is an important
information or signaling content in dividend announcements.
Like mot other aspects of
dividend policy, empirical studies of signaling have had mixed result. There is
clearly some information content in dividend announcements. However, it is
difficult to tell whether the stock price changes that follow increase or
decreases in dividends reflect only signaling effects or both signaling and
dividend preference. Still signaling effects should definitely be considered
when a firm is contemplating a change in dividend policy.
Clientele Effect
As we indicated earlier,
different groups, or clienteles of stockholders prefer different dividend
payout policies. For example retired individuals and university endowment funds
generally prefer cash income so they may want the firm to pay out a high
percentage of its earnings. Such investors (and pension funds) are often in low
or even zero tax brackets so taxes are of no concern. On the other hand,
stockholders in their peak earning years might prefer reinvestment, because
they have less need for current investment income and would simply reinvest
dividends received, after first paying income taxes on those dividends.
If a firm retains and reinvests
income rather than paying dividends those stockholders who need current income
would be disadvantaged. The value of their stock might increase but they would
be forced to go to the trouble and expense of selling off some of their shares
to obtain cash. Also some institutional investors (or trustees for individuals)
would be legally precluded from selling stock and then “spending capital”. On the
other hand, stockholders who are saving rather then spending dividends might
favor the low dividend policy for the less the firm pays out in dividends the
less these stockholders will have to pay in current taxes, and the less trouble
and expense they will have to go through to reinvest their after-tax dividends.
Therefore, investors who want current investment income should own shares in
high dividend payout firms, while investors with no need for current investment
income should own shares in low dividend payout firms. For example investors
seeking high cash income might invest in electric utilities, which averaged a
79 percent payout from 1991 through 1995, while those favoring growth could
invest in the semiconductor industry, which paid out only 7 percent.
To the extent that stockholders
can switch firms, a firm can change from one dividend payout policy to another
and then let stockholders who do not like the new policy sell to other
investors who do. However, frequent switching would be inefficient because of (1)
brokerage costs, (2) the likelihood that stockholders who are selling will have
to pay capital gains taxes, and (3) a possible shortage of investors who like
the firms newly adopted dividend policy. Thus, management should be hesitant to
change its dividend policy, because a change might cause current shareholders
to sell their stock, forcing the stock price down. Such a price decline might
be temporary, but it might also be permanent if few new investors are attracted
by the new dividend policy, then the stock price would remain depressed. Of
course, the new policy might attract an even larger clientele than the firm had
before in which case the stock price would rise.
Thursday, August 8, 2013
Dividends Versus Capital Gains : What Do Investors Prefer?
When deciding how much cash to
distribute to stockholders, financial managers must keep in mind that the
firm’s objective is to maximize shareholder value. Consequently, the target
payout ratio-defined as the percentage of net income to be paid out as cash
dividends –should be based in large part on investors, preferences for
dividends versus capital gains: do investors prefer (1) to have the firm
distribute income as cash dividends or (2) to have it either repurchase stock
or else plow the earnings back into the business, both of which should result
in capital gains? This preference can be considered in terms of the constant
growth stock valuation model:
D1
P0 = -------------
Ks - g
If the company increases the
payout ratio, it raises D1. This increase in the numerator, taken
alone, would cause the stock price to rise. However, if D1 is
raised, then less money will be available for reinvestment, that will cause the
expected growth rate to decline, and that would tend to lower the stock’s
price. Thus any change in payout policy will have two opposing effects.
Therefore, the firm’s optimal dividend policy must strike a balance between
current dividends and future growth so as to maximize the stock price.
In this section we examine three
theories of investor preference: (1) the dividend irrelevance theory, (2) the “bird-in-the-hand”
theory and (3) the tax preference theory.
Dividend Irrelevance Theory
It has been argued that dividend
policy has no effect on either the price of a firm’s stock or its cost of
capital. If dividend policy has no significant effects, then it would be
irrelevant. The principal proponents of the dividend irrelevance theory are Merton
Miller and Franco Modigliani (MM)1. They argued that the firm’s
value is determined only by its basic earning power and its business risk. In
other words, MM argued that the value of the firm depends only on the income
produced by its assets not on how this income is split between dividends and retained
earnings.
To understand MM’s argument that
dividend policy is irrelevant, recognize that any shareholder can construct his
or her own dividend policy. For example, if a firm does not pay dividends, a
shareholder who wants a 5 percent dividend can “create” it by selling 5 percent
of his or her stock. Conversely, if a company pays a higher dividend than an
investor desires, the investor can use the unwanted dividends to buy additional
shares of the company’s stock. If investors could buy and sell shares and thus
create their own dividend policy without incurring costs, then the firm’s
dividend policy would truly be irrelevant. Note, though that investors who want
additional dividends must incur brokerage costs to sell shares, and investors
who do not want dividends must first pay taxes on the unwanted dividends and
then incur brokerage costs to purchase shares with the after-tax dividends.
Since taxes and brokerage costs certainly exist, dividend policy may well be
relevant.
In developing their dividend
theory. MM made a number of assumptions, especially the absence of taxes and
brokerage costs. Obviously, taxes and brokerage costs do exist, so the MM
irrelevance theory may not be true. However, MM argued (correctly) that all
economic theories are based on simplifying assumptions, and that the validity
of a theory must be judged by empirical tests, not by the realism of its
assumptions. We will discuss empirical tests of MM’s dividend irrelevance
theory shortly.
Bird-in-the-Hand Theory
The principal conclusion of MM’s
dividend irrelevance theory is that dividend policy does not affect the
required rate of return on equity Ks. This conclusion has been hotly
debated in academic circles. In particular, Myron Gordon and John Lintner
argued that Ks decreases as the dividend payout is increased because
investors are less certain of receiving the capital gains which are supposed to
result from retaining earnings than they are of receiving dividend payments.2
Gordon and Lintner said, in effect that investors value a dollar of expected
dividends more highly than a dollar of expected capital gains because the
dividend yield component, D1/P0, is less risky than the g
component in the total expected return equation, Ks=D1/P0
+ g.
MM disagreed. They argued that Ks
is independent of dividend policy, which implies that investors are indifferent
between D1/P0 and g and, hence, between dividends and
capital gains. MM called the Gordon-Lintner argument the bird-in-the-hand
fallacy because, in MM’s view, most investors plan to reinvest their dividends
in the stock of the same or similar firms, and in any event the riskiness of
the firm’s cash flows to investors in the long run is determined by the
riskiness of operating cash flows not by dividend payout policy.
Tax Preference Theory
There are three tax-related
reasons for thinking that investors might prefer a low dividend payout to a
high payout: (1) Long-term capital gains are taxed at a maximum rate of 28
percent, whereas dividend income is taxed at effective rates which go up to
39.6 percent. Therefore, wealthy investors (who own most of the stock and
receive most of the dividends) might prefer to have companies retain and plow
earnings back into the business. Earnings growth would presumably lead to stock
price increases, and lower-taxed capital gains would be substituted fro
higher-taxed dividends. (2) Taxes are not paid on the gain until a stock is
sold. Due to time value effects, a dollar of taxes paid in the future has a
lower effective cost than a dollar paid today. (3) If a stock is held by
someone until he or she dies, no capital gains tax is due at all-the
beneficiaries who receive the stock can use the stocks’ value on the death day
as their cost basis and thus completely escape the capital gains tax.
Because of these tax advantages,
investors may prefer to have companies retain most of their earnings. If so
investors would be willing to pay more for low-payout companies than for
otherwise similar high-payout companies.
Monday, August 5, 2013
Capital Structure Decisions
In addition to the types of
analyses discussed above, firms generally consider the following factors when
making capital structure decisions:
1. Sales Stability. A firm whose sales are
relatively stable can safely take on more debt and incur higher fixed changes
than a company with unstable sales.
2. Asset structure. Firms whose assets are
suitable as security for loans tend to use debt rather heavily. General-purpose
assets which can be used by many businesses make good collateral. Whereas
special-purpose assets do not. Thus real estate companies are usually highly
leveraged, whereas companies involved in technological research are not.
3. Operating leverage. Other things the
same, a firm with less operating leverage is better able to employ financial
leverage because it will have less business risk. (This is discussed in greater
detail in Appendix 13.A.)
4. Growth rate. Other things the same,
faster-growing firms must rely more heavily on external capital. Further, the
flotation costs involved in selling common stock exceed those incurred when
selling debt, which encourages them to rely more heavily on debt. At the same
time, however rapidly growing firms often face greater uncertainty, which tends
to reduce their willingness to use debt.
5. Profitability. One often, observes that
firms with very high rates of return on investment use relatively little debt.
Although there is no theoretical justification for this fact, one practical
explanation is that very profitable firms such as Intel, Microsoft, and
Coca-Cola simply do not need to do much debt financing, Their high rates of
return enable them to do most of their financing with internally generated
funds.
6. Taxes. Interest is a deductible expense,
and deductions are most valuable to firms with high tax rates. Therefore the
higher a firm’s tax rate, the greater the advantage of debt.
7. Control. The effect of debt versus stock
on a management’s control position can influence capital structure. If management
currently has voting control (over 50 percent of the stock) but is not in a
position to buy any more stock, it may choose debt for new financings. On the
other hand management may it may choose debt for new financings. On the other
hand, management may decide to use equity if the firm’s financial situation is
so weak that the use of debt might subject it to serious risk of default,
because if the firm goes into default, the managers will almost surely lose
their jobs. However, if too little debt is used, management runs the risk of a
takeover. Thus, control considerations could lead to the use of either debt or
equity, because the type of capital that best protects management will very
from situation to situation. In any event, if management is at all insecure, it
will consider the control situation.
8. Management attitudes. Since no one can
prove that one capital structure will lead to higher stock prices than another,
management can exercise its own judgment about the proper capital structure.
Some managements tend to be more conservative than others and thus use less
debt than the average firm in their industry, whereas aggressive managements
use more debt in the quest for higher profits.
9. Lender and rating agency attitudes.
Regardless of managers own analyses of the proper leverage factors for their
firms, lenders and rating agencies attitudes frequently influence financial
structure decisions. In the majority of cases, the corporation discusses its
capital structure with lenders and rating agencies and gives much weight to
their advice. For example, one large utility was recently told by Moody and
Standard & Poor that its bonds would be downgraded if it issued more bonds.
This influenced its decision to finance its expansion with common equity.
10. Market conditions. Conditions in the stock
and bond markets undergo both long and short run changes that can have an important
bearing on a firm’s optimal capital structure. For example, during a recent
credit crunch, the junk bond market dried up and their was simply no market at
a reason able interest rate for any new long term bonds rated below triple B.
Therefore, low rated companies in need of capital were forced to go to the
stock market or to the short term debt market, regardless of their target capital
structures. When conditions eased, however these companies sold bonds to get
their capital structures back on target.
11. The firm’s internet condition. A firm’s
own internal condition can also have a bearing on its target capital structure.
For example, suppose a firm has just successfully completed an R&D program
and it forecasts higher earnings in the immediate future. However, the new
earnings are not yet anticipated by investors, hence are not reflected in the
stock price. This company would not want to issue stock it would prefer to
finance with debt until the higher earnings materialize and are reflected in
the stock price. Then it could sell an issue of common stock, retire the debt
and return to its target capital structure. This point was discussed earlier in
connection with asymmetric information and signaling.
12. Financial flexibility. An astute corporate
treasurer made this statement to the authors:
Our company can earn a lot more money
from good capital budgeting and operating decisions than from good financing
decisions. Indeed we are not sure exactly how financing decisions affect our
stock price, but we know for sure than having to turn down a promising venture
because funds are not available will reduce our long run profitability. For
this reason my primary goal as treasurer is to always be in a position to raise
the capital needed to support operations.
We also know
that when times are good we can raise capital with either stocks or bonds but
when times are bad, suppliers of capital are much more willing to make funds
available if we give them a secured position and this means debt. Further when
we sell a new issue of stock this sends a negative signal to investors, so
stock sales by a mature company such as ours are not desirable.
Putting all
these thoughts together gives rise to the goal of maintaining financial
flexibility, which from an operational viewpoint means maintaining adequate
reserve borrowing capacity. Determining an adequate reserve borrowing capacity
is judgmental bit it clearly depends on the factors discussed including the
firm’s forecasted need for funds, predicted capital market conditions
management’s confidence in its forecasts and the consequences of a capital
shortage.
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)